In an era of political polarization, Michael Bloomberg has the
rare ability to come up with policies that enrage everyone.
His latest pet project—banning large sodas, as a way of
fighting obesity in
New York
—has been ridiculed by both
Jon Stewart and John Boehner. And a recent Board of Health
hearing on the plan saw Democratic and Republican politicians
alike lining up to attack the idea, which would prohibit
restaurants, delis, sports arenas, movie theatres, and food
carts from selling any soft drinks larger than sixteen ounces.
Critics dismiss the ban as yet another expression of
Bloomberg’s nanny-state mentality and as a “feel-good
placebo” that’s doomed to fail. They’re right that the
ban is blatantly paternalist. But that doesn’t mean it
won’t work.
It’s
true that the ban will be easy to circumvent: if you want to
drink thirty-two ounces, you can just buy
two sixteen
-ounce servings. But Bloomberg’s proposal makes clever use of what
economists call “default bias.” If you offer a choice in
which one option is seen as a default, most people go for that
default option. People who are automatically enrolled in a
retirement plan, for instance, are more likely to stay with
their original plan than those who choose plans for
themselves. In countries where people have to choose to be an
organ donor, most people aren’t donors; in countries where
people have to actively say they don’t want to be an organ
donor, most are donors. The soda ban makes sixteen ounces or
less the default option for soda drinkers; if they want more,
they’ll have to make an extra effort.
An
executive at the American Beverage Association has dismissed
the plan, saying that “150 years of research finds that
people consume what they want.” Actually, the research shows
that what people “want” has a lot to do with how choices
are framed. In one well-known study, researchers put a bowl of
M&M’s on the concierge desk of an apartment building,
with a scoop attached and a sign below that said “Eat Your
Fill.” On alternating days, the experimenters changed the
size of the scoop—from a tablespoon to a quarter-cup scoop,
which was four times as big. If people really ate just “what
they want,” the amount they ate should have remained roughly
the same. But scoop size turned out to matter a lot: people
consumed much more when the scoop was big. This suggests that
most of us don’t have a fixed idea of how much we want;
instead, we look to outside cues—like the size of a package
or cup—to instruct us. And since the nineteen-seventies the
portion sizes offered by food companies and restaurants have
grown significantly larger. In 1974, the biggest drink
McDonald’s offered was twenty-one ounces. Today, that’s
roughly the size of a “small” drink at Burger King. In
effect, the scoops have got bigger, and consumption has risen
accordingly.
Of
course, if you don’t want the large soda, you needn’t
order it. Yet the mere existence of the supersize can change
your idea of how much you want to drink. In a classic
experiment by Itamar Simonson and Amos Tversky, people asked
to choose between a cheap camera and a pricier one with more
features were divided more or less equally between the two
options. But when a third option—a fancy, very expensive
camera—was added to the mix most people went for the
mid-range camera. The
very expensive camera made the middle one seem less
extravagant. In the same way, the fact that a large soda is
now forty ounces makes a twenty-ounce soda feel sensible.
Bloomberg’s ban is designed to flip this effect on its head:
if the largest soda you can order is sixteen ounces, a can of
Coke may start to seem like more than enough. Some food
researchers doubt that this will work, since so many of us are
used to the idea of large servings. But even our experience of
feeling satiated is highly malleable. In one experiment,
people ate meals of dramatically different sizes in the dark,
and those who were given much less food did not feel hungrier
than the others or rate their meals as much smaller. So once
people have a few sixteen-ounce drinks they may find that
sixteen ounces is plenty.
Many
economists would say that, if we want to discourage soda
consumption, taxing it—the way we do alcohol and
tobacco—would be more efficient than a ban. Some European
countries do have such taxes, but the idea has been a
political non-starter in
New York
. In any case, perhaps the most
cunning aspect of Bloomberg’s proposed ban is that it would
function as a kind of stealth tax on consumption, while
leaving average-sized sodas untouched. Currently, on a
per-ounce basis, large drinks are much cheaper than smaller
ones—which encourages people to supersize. The soda ban
should shift this.
Two sixteen
-ounce servings are bound to be more expensive than
one thirty-two
-ounce serving, which creates
another disincentive to drink more.
If
all this sounds as if
New York
’s soda consumers were about
to become the subjects of an elaborate social-science
experiment designed to reshape their behavior and desires,
well, that’s kind of true. But then we’ve been the subject
of just such an experiment, run by beverage and fast-food
companies, for the past forty years. If Bloomberg has his way,
we may start feeling like we’re white rats in a maze, but at
least there’s a good chance we’ll be thinner rats.
-- James
Surowiecki, The New Yorker,
August 13, 2012
|